Commentary

Wisconsin, Unions, and Collective Bargaining

It seems the public-sector union collective bargaining issue is far from over in Wisconsin or the rest of the country. Legal wrangling continues over whether or not the law passed by Republican legislators in Wisconsin greatly restricting state workers’ collective bargaining rights is, in fact, a law. After the Republicans found a loophole to get around a lack of a quorum when 14 Senate Democrats fled the state to prevent a vote, several lawsuits were filed to challenge the bill’s passage. Wisconsin Circuit Court Judge Maryann Sumi issued a temporary restraining order last week preventing the law from going into effect, but on Friday the state’s nonpartisan Legislative Reference Bureau went ahead and published the law, which normally triggers a law’s implementation. It appears that the state Supreme Court will be the ultimate arbiter of the law’s fate.

Union workers in other states are still rallying to demonstrate support for the Wisconsin state workers’ unions, too. On Saturday in downtown Los Angeles, thousands of unionized teaches, nurses, Teamsters, electricians, truckers, actors, screenwriters, longshoremen, telephone technicians, and others marched and rallied to show support for Wisconsin state employees still fighting the budget reform and public union collective bargaining bill, and to voice their opposition to similar measures—actual or potential—in other states.

One of the best and most concise analyses I’ve seen of the whole union and collective bargaining issue—particularly in the context of the economics of unions—was written by Jeffrey Miron, Senior Lecturer and Director of Undergraduate Studies at Harvard University and Senior Fellow at the Cato Institute, recently in a post at The Freeman’s Anything Peaceful blog. The following passage contains Miron’s pearls of wisdom.

The right question is not whether unions are good or bad. A union is a voluntary association of employees that attempts to increase the compensation of its members by bargaining collectively with an employer. No one should object to such an association, nor to its desire to improve its members’ welfare. Unions per se are neither good nor bad.

The right question, instead, is whether policy should attempt to give unions more power than they would have under laissez faire. To answer that question, consider the economic effects of such policies.

Without help from policy, unions might still form and attempt to bargain collectively, and some employers might agree because they find collective bargaining easier than negotiating compensation with every employee. The ability of these “free market” unions to increase wages, however, would be modest: if their demands implied compensation much above the individually negotiated levels, employers would just refuse to bargain with unions.

But this outcome — in which unions have little effect on wages and benefits — is exactly what economic efficiency demands. Absent policy protection, employers will hire additional labor when the value of the extra output this labor can produce exceeds the compensation the labor would require to voluntarily supply this effort. Any policy that raises labor’s cost above this level means that employers will hire fewer people and produce an inefficiently low level of output, or produce in an inefficient manner by substituting relatively expensive capital for what could be relatively cheap labor.

Given this economic reality, why does anyone support policies that protect unions?

Presumably, to redistribute income to union members. Protections for unions indeed have this effect, but this kind of redistribution makes no sense.

Union protections do not help the truly poor; they raise the wage of those who would earn a moderate wage without union protections. Indeed, by encouraging firms to hire fewer people, unions mean increased income for some but a zero income for others, thus exacerbating poverty. In extreme cases, union protections drive businesses overseas in search of cheaper labor, meaning large reductions in employment.

Union protections also raise the cost of goods and services in unionized sectors by increasing the cost of production. This means that everyone, including the poor, face higher prices for cars, houses, transportation, and so on. In the public arena, union protections mean higher costs of government services, which adversely affects everyone but especially the poor.

The bottom line is that government policy should not protect unions in any way. This means no requirements for employers to bargain collectively, no rules that force all employees to be covered by union contracts, and no impediments to hiring non-union labor. Similarly, it means no restrictions on firing strikers, or closing plants, or hiring replacement workers.

See also:

“Comparing Private Sector and Government Worker Salaries”

How California’s Public Pension System Broke (and How to Fix It)

The Gathering Pension Storm: How Government Pension Plans Are Breaking the Bank and Strategies for Reform